Ph.D. Student Placement

Congratulations to our Ph.D. students for their success in the job market. They will be heading to the following places:

Omer Ali: Analysis Group

Adrien d’Avernas: Stockholm School of Economics

Xue Hu: Amazon

Mat Miller: Amazon

Ruoyao Shi: UC Riverside

Chad Stecher: Rensselaer Polytechnic Institute

Colin Weiss: Federal Reserve Board

Sibo Yan: KPMG

Gabriel Zaourak: World Bank

Andreas Gulyas: University of Mannheim

Lauren Lucido Watkins

Ever since the 5th grade, Lauren Lucido Watkins knew she wanted to be a Bruin. There was no rhyme or reason, nor strong family legacy ties – Lauren was simply drawn to the prestige that came with the name and the energy that radiated from everyone who spoke about the university. Without ever considering a second option, she accepted her offer and graduated from UCLA in 2011 with a BA in Business Economics and a minor in Accounting.

Lauren Lucido Watkins

Lauren has always been a strategic thinker and natural problem-solver. Lauren attributes her first venture into the realm of strategy and consulting as a core member for the Daily Bruin, first working as an intern, moving to internal advertising sales, and ultimately working as the assistant manager during her junior and senior years. In a time where the technological revolution was on the cusp of breaking through, Lauren and other members of the Daily Bruin were tasked with countering the demise of print paper and shift to online news platforms. While figuring out how to generate revenue beyond print and assessing the internal structure of the Daily Bruin, Lauren realized the importance of aligning your team with your business needs. Without a strong people strategy, she knew that business changes couldn’t follow. Lauren followed her passion, which culminated into an internship in Los Angeles with Deloitte Consulting in their Human Capital practice.

Lauren excelled as a top analyst while at Deloitte. She worked in their organization and talent group for two years before being approached by Christian Dior, who at the time was looking for business-minded candidates to take part in their re-launched management training program. Lauren knew that an opportunity in high fashion may not come again, so she decided to take a leap of faith, recognizing a greater end goal, and leave her job at Deloitte. Within a week, Lauren went from being a consultant advising clients, to working the floor at the Christian Dior Boutique on Rodeo Drive learning all facets of the luxury retail landscape. Such a drastic change in environment is no easy feat. Lauren believes her time spent at UCLA working at the Daily Bruin contributed to her successful transition between two very distinct worlds. She draws parallels between working at the Daily Bruin and her first work experiences at Christian Dior, both times in which she was a part of a group of people whose main focus was working as a team to grow the business in a fast-moving environment.

The Daily Bruin was not Lauren’s only extracurricular activity at UCLA. Lauren is a sister of Kappa Alpha Theta, serving as the Internal Social Chair and VP of Membership, and was the Consulting Director of the Undergraduate Business Society during her senior year. In terms of academics, her favorite class she took while at UCLA was Real Estate Investments, taught in tandem with professors and students from the Anderson School of Management. She has used many of the learnings to assess investments in her own life, including purchasing a home in San Francisco.

Upon transitioning to Christian Dior, Lauren spent one year in Beverly Hills focused on client development strategies and was then promoted to Christian Dior’s New York flagship where she was tasked at driving sales and overseeing the shoe department. Fast-forward to present day and Lauren has scaled the corporate ladder, now the Assistant Boutique Manager for the Christian Dior boutique in San Francisco, which she helped to open last year.

As a lover of high fashion myself, I was keen on hearing about how Lauren acquired such a vast knowledge of the high fashion realm in order to be working at one of the powerhouses in the industry. Her advice was to constantly stay active in obtaining knowledge and keeping an eye on the ever-changing landscape of fashion. I also asked her if there was any advice she wished she could say to her college-self. “Be fearless, take risks, and do [things] you’re passionate about.” Lauren reminded us that unless you put yourself out there, you can never truly reap the rewards from all the opportunities in life.

Written by Katie Kim, Undergraduate

Click here to see more Alumni Interviews.

Recruiting Talent

Mortiz Meyer-ter-Vehn

The success of most firms is built upon hundreds of individuals who take thousands of decisions, making it critical to identify and recruit the best talent. Such human capital is a key source of competitive advantage in a wide range of industries, from service to technology. For instance, the standing of a university depends more on the quality of its professors than on its real estate. Talent is also critical for consultants, salesmen and firms like Netflix, whose human resource manual states “One outstanding employee gets more done and costs less than two adequate employees. We endeavor to have only outstanding employees”.

Differences in talent across firms perpetuate through hiring because talented managers have better judgment and better information. For example, in academia, a star professor can easily evaluate the quality of an applicant’s research. And, at Netflix, talented managers can use their professional connections to investigate a potential recruit.

Simon Board

Based on these tenets – that talent matters and perpetuates through hiring – professors Simon Board, Moritz Meyer-ter-Vehn, and Tomasz Sadzik propose a new model of firm dynamics in their working paper entitled “Recruiting Talent”. The key contribution of the paper is to place talent at center stage, in comparison to traditional models of firm dynamics that characterize firms through their stock of capital or labor. The resulting model generates persistent differences between firms’ talent, productivity and wages, consistent with the large dispersion found in the empirical literature. A firm’s stock of talent thus gives it an advantage in identifying future talent and provides a sustainable competitive advantage.

Tomasz Sadzik

The first step in the analysis is to show that firms with many talented employees optimally pay high wages and attract the best applicants. Intuitively, skilled recruiters have a comparative advantage in hiring from a high-wage applicant pool with a balance of talented workers, rather than hiring from a low-wage pool in which few talented applicants remain. If firms start off initially similar then, over time, better endowed firms accumulate talent, while the worse endowed hire from poor, deteriorating applicant pools and lose talent. Countering this is the natural regression to mediocrity that results from noise in the hiring process. The economy then converges to a steady state that exhibits persistent heterogeneity in wages, talent and productivity where these two forces offset each other. While low-quality firms could in principle catch up by posting higher wages and hiring more talented workers, it is not profitable for them to do so.

Building on this model, the paper generates a rich set of predictions. An increase in screening skills, say, due to technological innovation, raises the dispersion of wages and the segregation of workers across firms, helping to explain recent trends documented in the empirical literature. The paper also cautions against splurging on “super-stars” for firms that wish to rise in the rankings. The authors show that such a strategy may be a waste of money when the current organization lacks the capabilities to identify the stars of tomorrow; a gradual increase in wages is preferable. Finally, the results show that welfare is increased by policies that reduce wage inequality, lowering the dispersion of talent and the segregation of workers across firms.

Michela Giorcelli wins Cole Grant

Professor Michela Giorcelli was awarded the Cole Research Grants-in-Aid for post-Doctoral Research by the Economic History Association for her project on “The Marshall Plan and the European and US Economies After WWII”. The Cole Grants are annually awarded to recent Ph.D. recipients to support research in economic history.

Danwei Chen

2016 Robert D. & Margaret A. Wark Memorial Scholarship Recipient

Biography: Danwei Chen is a third-year student at UCLA pursuing a major in Economics and minor in Accounting. Having completed elementary through high school in Wisconsin, she is enjoying discovering all that Los Angeles has to offer. Danwei currently works for the Laurence and Lori Fink Center for Finance & Investments within the UCLA Anderson Graduate School of Management, where she has learned much about the finance industry. She is passionate about community involvement and serves as Vice President-Operations of Colleges Against Cancer at UCLA, the collegiate extension of the American Cancer Society. Danwei recently studied abroad at the London School of Economics, during which time she took courses in finance and economics and fostered her passions for travel and global cultures. She also likes to spend time hiking, playing/watching tennis, and trying new foods.

Future Plans: Danwei is excited about the applications of her education and is working towards a career in finance. This summer, she will be completing a Summer Analyst position at Pacific Alternative Asset Management Company in Irvine, California. She hopes to work full-time in the investment management field upon graduation and eventually pursue a Master’s in Business Administration.

What does the scholarship mean to me?: I feel incredibly honored to be selected as a recipient of the Robert D. and Margaret A. Wark Memorial Scholarship. I am extremely grateful to the Wark Family for their generosity in supporting my education. With this scholarship, I’m able to focus more time and effort on academic, professional, and extracurricular pursuits. I’m touched by the Wark Family’s giving values and hope to someday pay it forward to future generations of Bruins. In the meantime, I will strive to honor this recognition by continuing to work hard in the remainder of my time at UCLA and the start of my career.

Inference using Machine Learning

Machine learning (ML) methods, developed mostly by computer scientists and statisticians, have brought remarkable success in solving prediction problems, especially with high-dimensional and complicated or, simply, big data. These methods have been used with great success, for example, in spam filtering and computer vision, among many other things.

In economics, however, prediction problems are of limited interest, and instead, the problem of measuring causal parameters, including various treatment effects, is much more important. Therefore, there has recently been an increasing amount of work in the econometrics literature trying to apply ML methods for estimation of causal parameters. One of the findings in this literature is that naively applying ML methods for estimation of causal parameters leads to unsatisfactory results: since ML methods are heavily regularized, ML-based causal parameter estimators are substantially biased, which leads to suboptimal precision of these estimators. Moreover, because of the bias, it is hard to study distributional properties of these estimators, which makes inference based on these estimators overly complicated.

In an attempt to overcome these difficulties, Denis Chetverikov (UCLA) has developed a novel method called Double Machine Learning (DML), in a joint project with Victor Chernozhukov (MIT), Mert Demirer (MIT), Esther Duflo (MIT), Christian Hansen (Chicago Booth), Whitney Newey (MIT), and James Robins (Harvard). This method is based on the observation that it is typically possible to represent the causal parameter of interest as a function of the solution of several prediction problems such that the bias in the solution of these prediction problems has minimal effect on the causal parameter itself. As long as such a function can be constructed, the DML method uses ML algorithms to solve each prediction problem separately in the first stage and then plugs in the solutions into the function giving the causal parameter of interest in the second stage. The authors show that by combining the DML method with a certain cross-fitting procedure, one can construct approximately unbiased and efficient estimators of the causal parameters, which have as high precision as possible, under very mild regularity conditions and allowing for a wide variety of ML methods to be used in the first stage. The authors also explain how the function relating the causal parameter and the solution of the prediction problems can be constructed in most commonly used econometric models via so-called Neyman orthogonal scores, which are extensively studied the literature on semiparametric estimation.

As an example illustrating the applicability of the DML method, the authors study the effect of institutions on economic growth following up on Acemoglu, Johnson, and Robinson (2001), “The colonial origins of comparative development: An empirical investigation,’’ American Economic Review. Estimating the effect of institutions on output is complicated by the clear potential for simultaneity between institutions and output: better institutions may lead to higher incomes, but higher incomes may also lead to the development of better institutions. To help overcome this simultaneity, AJR use mortality rates for early European settlers as an instrument for institution quality. The validity of this instrument hinges on the argument that (i) settlers set up better institutions in places where they are more likely to establish long-term settlements; (ii) where they are likely to settle for the long term is related to settler mortality at the time of initial colonization; and (iii) institutions are highly persistent. The exclusion restriction for the instrumental variable is then motivated by the argument that GDP, while persistent, is unlikely to be strongly influenced by mortality in the previous century, or earlier, except through institutions. AJR also note that their instrumental variable strategy will be invalidated if other factors are also highly persistent and related to the development of institutions and to the country’s GDP. A leading candidate for such a factor, as they discuss, is geography. AJR address this by assuming that the confounding effect of geography is adequately captured by a linear term in distance from the equator. However, if the true geography effect is non-linear, which can be expected, the AJR estimator may be substantially biased due to misspecification, and the DML method allows to overcome this problem by flexibly controlling for the geography effect. By applying the DML method to the AJR data, the authors confirm the AJR results that there is a substantial effect of institutions on country income, but the effect is smaller than reported by AJR. Moreover, the precision of the DML estimator is higher than that of the AJR estimator.

The paper can be found here.